Population, Income and Growth: "Is the Semi-Permanent "Gunpowder Empire" Historical Scenario Plausible? Perhaps Not..."
From Brad DeLong:
Riffing off of yesterday's: : "'Gunpowder Empire': Should We Generalize Mark Elvin's High-Level Equilibrium Trap?"...
A generation ago Michael Kremer wrote a superb paper: Michael Kremer (1993): "Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to 1990", Quarterly Journal of Economics 108:3 (August), pp. 681-716 http://tinyurl.com/dl20160727a.
Kremer saw human populations as growing at an increasing rate over
time. Population reached approximately 4 million by 10000 BC, 50 million
by 1000 BC, and 170 million by the year 1. Population then reached 265
million by the year 1000, 425 million by 1500, and 720 million by 1750
before the subsequent explosion of the British Industrial Revolution and
the subsequent spread of Modern Economic Growth.
Michael Kremer then developed this association between higher
global population levels and faster population (and global real GDP, and
global total factor productivity) growth into a "two heads are better
than one" theory of long-run economic growth:
No matter where the economy starts, it winds up in region B....
Once the trajectory is in region B, it remains there, with population
and income both increasing indefinitely.
Income must eventually reach
y*, the [demographic transition] level above which population growth
slows.... As income rises above y*, population growth rates decline. If Φ
= 1, so that the level of technology enters the research production
function linearly, growth rates of technology continue to increase
because population continues to increase.
If 1 > Φ... growth rates of technology are likely to continue to
increase for some period.... In summary, if population adjusts to
income at finite speed... income will gradually rise over time... there
will eventually be a demographic transition... [followed by] steady
state growth rates of population, technology, and income...
In Kremer's model, population will grow and eventually population
will be high enough that research and development will proceed fast
enough to push income per capita high enough to trigger the demographic
transition and thus break the Malthusian proportional link between
resources and technology on the one hand and population on the other.
After that link is broken, economic growth will predominantly take the
form not of Malthusian increases in population but rather Industrial
Revolution and Modern Economic Growth increases in living standards and
labor productivity.
The breakthrough to an Industrial Revolution, Modern Economic Growth,
and our present prosperous global post-industrial economy is therefore
baked into the cake. It is an all-but-inevitable event in human history
produced by the simple fact that when it comes to generating useful
ideas two heads are better than one: "the fundamental nonrivalry of
technology as described by Paul Romer (1986)..."
The alternative view to the inevitability of the breakthrough is that
the breakthrough to the Industrial Revolution and the subsequent
knock-on transition to Modern Economic Growth was a lucky throw of the
historical dice--that while Kremer's model has something like our
economic world today as our inevitable destiny, the world might well be
substantially otherwise and remain substantially otherwise for millennia
if not longer. The current poster child for
British-Industrial-Revolution-a-lucky accident is Robert Allen, and his
excellent "The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective":
It was not Newtonian science that inclined British inventors and
entrepreneurs to seek machines that raised labour productivity but the
rising cost of labour... due to... Britain’s success in the global
economy... in part the result of state policy... [and] Britain['s] vast
and readily worked coal deposits.... The necessary R&D was
profitable in Britain (under British conditions) but unprofitable
elsewhere....
The theory advanced here explains the technological breakthroughs
of the industrial revolution in terms of the economic base of
society–natural resources, international trade, profit opportunities.
Through their impact on wages and prices, these prime movers affected
both the demand for technology and its supply...
Why did the industrial revolution lead to modern economic
growth?... Wouldn’t the French, or the Germans, or the Italians, have
produced an industrial revolution by another route? Weren’t there
alternative paths to the twentieth century?... The nineteenth century
engineering industry was a spin-off of the coal industry.... The British
inventions of the eighteenth century–cheap iron and the steam engine,
in particular–were so transformative... because of the possibilities
they created for the further development of technology. Technologies
invented in France–in paper production, glass, knitting–did not lead to
general mechanization or globalization....
There is no reason to believe that French technology would have led
to the engineering industry, the general mechanization of industrial
processes, the railway, the steam ship, or the global economy. In other
words, there was only one route to the twentieth century–and it went
through northern Britain...
Allen may be right and he may be wrong. But let's explore what the
consequences are of assuming that he is right--that the British
Industrial Revolution was a lucky, discontinuous break. Suppose that
without the British Industrial Revolution global economic history would
have continued along a business-as-usual track, suppose that the British
Industrial Revolution required British commitment to its
fiscal-military state followed by the victories at sea that wound up
funneling the globe's mercantile profits into the island, and so raising
wages. What would the world have looked like had the Protestant Winds of 1588 and 1689
not blown, and Britain been ruled by a Catholic Stuart Dynasty French-
or Spanish-subsidized client dynasty unwilling to fight the Second
Hundred Years War?
Kremer's (1993) model then allows us to ask the question: How long
would it have taken--in the absence of eighteenth century Britain--to
get the ball rolling....MUCH MORE