Despite all the attention and investment
that Silicon Valley’s recent start-ups have received, they have done
little but lose money: Uber, Lyft, WeWork, Pinterest, and Snapchat have
consistently failed to turn profits, with Uber’s cumulative losses
exceeding $25 billion. Perhaps even more notorious are bankrupt and
discredited start-ups such as Theranos, Luckin Coffee, and Wirecard,
which were plagued with management failures, technical problems, or even
outright fraud that auditors failed to notice.1
What’s going on? There is no immediately obvious reason why this
generation of start-ups should be so financially disastrous. After all,
Amazon incurred losses for many years, but eventually grew to become one
of the most profitable companies in the world, even as Enron and
WorldCom were mired in accounting scandals. So why can’t today’s
start-ups also succeed? Are they exceptions, or part of a larger, more
systemic problem?
Today’s big losses are not what Silicon Valley founders and
futurists predicted. Artificial intelligence, driverless vehicles, ride
sharing, blockchain, virtual reality, augmented reality, and the
Internet of Things were supposed to change the world, enabling a
dramatic increase in productivity growth. The resulting wealth was
expected to be so huge that we would be able to support the unemployed
with a universal basic income (UBI). Indeed, Andrew Yang, a successful
entrepreneur, ran for president in 2020 on a platform whose most notable
feature was a UBI pledge.
Furthermore, all these developments were supposed to be part of a
larger technological revolution: according to many leading commentators
and entrepreneurs, we are purportedly living in the most innovative
time ever. And venture capitalists seem to agree: their funding set a
five-year record between 2015 and 2019, with investments in a wide
variety of industries, and 2020 set a new single-year record.2
My analysis of start-ups, however, shows that the big losses suffered by Uber, Lyft, WeWork, Pinterest, and Snapchat—greater than 50 percent of revenues annually—are just the tip of the iceberg. More than 90 percent of America’s “unicorns”—start-ups valued at $1 billion or more while privately held (before IPOs)—lost
money in 2019 or 2020, even though more than half of them were founded
over ten years ago. And a similar trend of losses holds for European,
Indian, and Chinese start-ups. Of similar importance, recent analyses of
venture capital (VC) firms show that returns on investments in VCs have
barely exceeded those of public stock markets over the past twenty-five
years, and their current losses suggest that returns will fall even
further. Indeed, the low profitability of start-ups is a reflection of
broader trends in the economy: the slowing productivity growth
documented by Robert Gordon; stagnating innovation observed by Tyler
Cowen; falling research productivity discussed by Anne Marie Knott,
Nicholas Bloom, and others; and the declining impact of Nobel Prize
research recently noted by Patrick Collinson and Michael Nielsen.3
In this article, I first discuss the abundant evidence for low
returns on VC investments in the contemporary market. Second, I
summarize the performance of start-ups founded twenty to fifty years
ago, in an era when most start-ups quickly became profitable, and the
most successful ones rapidly achieved top-100 market capitalization.
Third, I contrast these earlier, more successful start-ups with Silicon
Valley’s current set of “unicorns,” the most successful of today’s
start-ups. Fourth, I discuss why today’s start-ups are doing worse than
those of previous generations and explore the reasons why technological
innovation has slowed in recent years. Fifth, I offer some brief
proposals about what can be done to fix our broken start-up system.
Systemic problems will require systemic solutions, and thus major
changes are needed not just on the part of venture capitalists but also
in our universities and business schools.
America’s Failing Venture Capital System
A 2020 report by Morgan Stanley4
documents several key trends in venture capital, particularly the
falling rate of returns over the last forty years (these findings are
summarized in figure 1). Investments in VC funds by individuals and
institutions have risen over the last twenty years, as have VC
investments in start-ups, the latter reaching a record high in recent
years. Yet returns on VC investment fell dramatically in the mid to
late 1990s and have stayed low ever since, now barely higher than those
of major stock market indices, an astonishing change when one considers
the far higher risks associated with funding start-ups.
Within this twenty-year period, several major changes occurred in
our start-up system that have contributed to these low returns.5
First, investor exits for most start-ups, at least until 2020, are now
largely accomplished by acquisition, rather than by taking companies
public through an initial public offering (IPO) on the stock market. The
problem here is that the returns on investment from an acquisition are
typically much smaller than those from an IPO, and thus the trend
towards acquisitions is probably one reason for the falling returns for
VC over the last twenty-five years. Second, among those start-ups that
do go public, the percent that are unprofitable at the time of their IPO
has increased dramatically over the last few decades, exceeding 80
percent in recent years, according to analysis by Jay Ritter of the
University of Florida.6
This increase has continued despite the falling overall percentage of
IPOs versus acquisitions, a change that should have caused the
percentage of unprofitable start-ups at IPO to fall.
These two trends together form a vicious circle. Lower profitability
at the time of IPO naturally leads to smaller share price increases and
thus to lower returns for start-up IPOs. These lower IPO returns in turn
discourage start-ups from going public and thus drive the trend toward
acquisition. But without profitability, incumbents will be unwilling to
pay high prices for the start-ups that they acquire, and so returns on
acquisitions will also fall. Lower acquisition valuations in turn affect
IPO valuations. Poor IPO performance and low acquisition prices thus
reinforce each other, and jointly lead to poor returns for the original
investors in VC funds.
This decline in returns for venture capital is a serious problem for
the U.S. economy, not only because it suggests that innovation is less
profitable than in the past, but also because it significantly affects
the investments of major institutions such as pension funds and
university endowments. As shown in the previously cited Morgan
Stanley report,7
these institutions have steadily increased their investments in VC
funds since 1970. These institutions also invest in start-up IPOs, and
the data discussed in the next section indicate that pre-pandemic
returns for investors in unicorn IPOs were negative.
Venture capitalists will disagree with this analysis. They will
emphasize that some VC funds are actually making money because returns
are heavily skewed, and thus, overall, the system is working. This
objection is partly correct: as shown in the Morgan Stanley report,8
a small percentage of investments does provide high returns, and these
high returns for top-performing VC funds persist over subsequent
quarters. Although this data does not demonstrate that select VCs
consistently earn solid profits over decades, it does suggest that these
VCs are achieving good returns. Therefore, such funds might still be
considered good investments, despite broader trends.
From a public policy standpoint, however, market averages are more
important than the individual returns of a few successful VCs, because
most investors cannot reliably distinguish between high- and low-return
funds. After all, the notion that high risk requires higher returns is
an old one, taught in every introductory finance course, yet the VC
system, on average, is not providing this risk premium. Thus, the VC
system bears a closer resemblance to another form of risk-taking:
gambling. Gambling also consistently offers low average returns but
occasionally produces large payouts that are heavily skewed to a few big
winners. And gamblers, like VC funds, tend to place their bets in the
expectation that they will win one of these rare jackpots. But
policymakers and the public should realize that average returns ought to
be higher for risky investments than less risky ones. If they are not,
it is time to rethink the value of VC.
A glance at the rest of the developed world suggests that these
problems of VC-funded start-ups are not exclusively American. The rest
of the world got a late start with venture capital, but by the end of
the 2010s other nations were also setting new records in VC
investments, particularly China and India. By June 2020, the number of
unicorn start-ups in China (227) had nearly equaled the number in
America (233). And global unicorns have now reached an enormous $1.9
trillion in total value.9
But, as I shall discuss below, the lack of VC profitability is a global
problem, with Chinese funds earning only slightly better returns than
American ones.10
The Start-Up Successes of the Late Twentieth Century
There was a time when venture capital generated big returns for
investors, employees, and customers alike, both because more start-ups
were profitable at an earlier stage and because some start-ups achieved
high market capitalization relatively quickly. Profits are an important
indicator of economic and technological growth, because they signal that
a company is providing more value to its customers than the costs it is
incurring.
A number of start-ups founded in the late twentieth century have had
an enormous impact on the global economy, quickly reaching both
profitability and top-100 market capitalization. Among these are the
so-called faamng (Facebook, Amazon,
Apple, Microsoft, Netflix, and Google), which represented more than 25
percent of the S&P’s total market capitalization and more than 80
percent of the 2020 increase in the S&P’s total value at one point—in other words, the most valuable and fastest-growing companies in America in recent years.
Rapidly growing start-ups of this type merit attention both because
they are arguably the main factor driving returns to venture capital—rather than the average profitability of all start-ups—and because they are the principal cause of the “creative destruction” celebrated by Joseph Schumpeter11
and other economists. As can be seen in figure 2, these giants reached
profitability and top-100 market capitalization relatively quickly:
Thirteen were profitable by year five, and another nine by year ten.
Ten achieved top-100 market capitalization by year ten, and sixteen by
year fifteen. Only one took longer than ten years to become profitable.
Amazon and Qualcomm became profitable in year ten, a relatively long
time within this group but far outpacing contemporary unicorns such as
Uber, WeWork, Snapchat, and Pinterest, which still suffer losses greater
than 50 percent of revenues at year ten or later.
Many of the successful start-ups of the late twentieth century
created value for workers as well as investors. In addition to
high-paying jobs for semiconductor engineers, software engineers,
laboratory scientists, and other white-collar workers, many of them
also created well-paying blue-collar jobs—particularly
the semiconductor manufacturers and other hardware companies that once
employed thousands of workers in their production facilities. In this
respect, also, they outshine the unicorns of more recent years, none of
which employs production workers, and few—if any—pay
adequate wages to their blue-collar employees. Uber, Lyft, and other
gig-work start-ups are major contributors to income inequality and thus
have drawn significant political backlash—a reaction resulting in regulations that could bring about their ultimate collapse.
A Cornibus Unicornium
In the contemporary start-up economy, “unicorns” are purportedly
“disrupting” almost every industry from transportation to real estate,
with new business software, mobile apps, consumer hardware, internet
services, biotech, and AI products and services.12
But the actual performance of these unicorns both before and after the
VC exit stage contrasts sharply with the financial successes of the
previous generation of start-ups, and suggests that they are
dramatically overvalued.
Figure 3 shows the profitability distribution of seventy-three
unicorns and ex-unicorns that were founded after 2013 and have released
net income and revenue figures for 2019 and/or 2020.13
In 2019, only six of the seventy-three unicorns included in figure 3
were profitable, while for 2020, seven of seventy were. The six
profitable start-ups in 2019 included three financial technology
(fintech) firms (GreenSky, Oportun, and Square) and one company each in
e-commerce (Etsy), video communications (Zoom), and solar energy
services (Sunrun). In 2020, three of these firms became unprofitable
(Oportun, Square, and Sunrun), and four others became profitable: three
e-commerce companies (Peloton, Purple Innovation, and Wayfair) and one
cloud storage service (Dropbox). Thus, a remarkably small fraction of
start-up unicorns has achieved profitability, despite the fact that
forty-five of the seventy-three analyzed here were founded over ten
years ago. By contrast, twenty-two of the twenty-four start-ups listed
above in figure 2—including Amazon and Qualcomm, which lagged in achieving profitability—were earning profits already by year ten....
....MUCH MORE