N.N. Taleb "The Most Intolerant Wins: The Dictatorship of the Small Minority"
Via his Medium site, August 14, 2016:
(Chapter from Skin in the Game)
How
Europe will eat Halal — Why you don’t have to smoke in the smoking
section — Your food choices on the fall of the Saudi king –How to
prevent a friend from working too hard –Omar Sharif ‘s conversion — How
to make a market collapse
The best example I know that gives insights into the functioning of a
complex system is with the following situation. It suffices for an
intransigent minority –a certain type of intransigent minorities –to
reach a minutely small level, say three or four percent of the total
population, for the entire population to have to submit to their
preferences. Further, an optical illusion comes with the dominance of
the minority: a naive observer would be under the impression that the
choices and preferences are those of the majority. If it seems absurd,
it is because our scientific intuitions aren’t calibrated for that
(fughedabout scientific and academic intuitions and snap judgments; they
don’t work and your standard intellectualization fails with complex
systems, though not your grandmothers’ wisdom).
The
main idea behind complex systems is that the ensemble behaves in way
not predicted by the components. The interactions matter more than the
nature of the units. Studying individual ants will never
(one can safely say never for most such situations), never give us an
idea on how the ant colony operates. For that, one needs to understand
an ant colony as an ant colony, no less, no more, not a collection of
ants. This is called an “emergent” property of the whole, by which parts and whole
differ because what matters is the interactions between such parts. And
interactions can obey very simple rules. The rule we discuss in this
chapter is the minority rule.
The
minority rule will show us how it all it takes is a small number of
intolerant virtuous people with skin in the game, in the form of
courage, for society to function properly.
This
example of complexity hit me, ironically, as I was attending the New
England Complex Systems institute summer barbecue. As the hosts were
setting up the table and unpacking the drinks, a friend who was
observant and only ate Kosher dropped by to say hello. I offered him a
glass of that type of yellow sugared water with citric acid people
sometimes call lemonade, almost certain that he would reject it owing to
his dietary laws. He didn’t. He drank the liquid called lemonade, and
another Kosher person commented: “liquids around here are Kosher”. We
looked at the carton container. There was a fine print: a tiny symbol, a
U inside a circle, indicating that it was Kosher.
The symbol will be detected by those who need to know and look for the
minuscule print. As to others, like myself, I had been speaking prose
all these years without knowing, drinking Kosher liquids without knowing
they were Kosher liquids.
Figure 1 The lemonade container with the circled U indicating it is (literally) Kosher.
Criminals With Peanut Allergies
A
strange idea hit me. The Kosher population represents less than three
tenth of a percent of the residents of the United States. Yet, it
appears that almost all drinks are Kosher. Why? Simply because going
full Kosher allows the producer, grocer, restaurant, to not have to
distinguish between Kosher and nonkosher for liquids, with special
markers, separate aisles, separate inventories, different stocking
sub-facilities. And the simple rule that changes the total is as
follows:
A Kosher (or halal) eater will never eat nonkosher (or nonhalal) food , but a nonkosher eater isn’t banned from eating kosher.
Or, rephrased in another domain:
A disabled person will not use the regular bathroom but a nondisabled person will use the bathroom for disabled people.
Granted,
sometimes, in practice, we hesitate to use the bathroom with the
disabled sign on it owing to some confusion –mistaking the rule for the
one for parking cars, under the belief that the bathroom is reserved for
exclusive use by the handicapped.
Someone
with a peanut allergy will not eat products that touch peanuts but a
person without such allergy can eat items without peanut traces in them.
Which
explains why it is so hard to find peanuts on airplanes and why schools
are peanut-free (which, in a way, increases the number of persons with
peanut allergies as reduced exposure is one of the causes behind such
allergies).
Let us apply the rule to domains where it can get entertaining:
An honest person will never commit criminal acts but a criminal will readily engage in legal acts.
Let us call such minority an intransigent group, and the majority a flexible one. And the rule is an asymmetry in choices.
I
once pulled a prank on a friend. Years ago when Big Tobacco were hiding
and repressing the evidence of harm from secondary smoking, New York
had smoking and nonsmoking sections in restaurants (even airplanes had,
absurdly, a smoking section). I once went to lunch with a friend
visiting from Europe: the restaurant only had availability in the
smoking sections. I convinced the friend that we needed to buy
cigarettes as we had to smoke in the smoking section. He complied.
Two
more things. First, the geography of the terrain, that is, the spatial
structure, matters a bit; it makes a big difference whether the
intransigents are in their own district or are mixed with the rest of
the population. If the people following the minority rule lived in
Ghettos, with their separate small economy, then the minority rule would
not apply. But, when a population has an even spatial distribution, say
the ratio of such a minority in a neighborhood is the same as that in
the village, that in the village is the same as in the county, that in
the county is the same as that in state, and that in the sate is the
same as nationwide, then the (flexible) majority will have to submit to
the minority rule. Second, the cost structure matters quite a bit. It
happens in our first example that making lemonade compliant with Kosher
laws doesn’t change the price by much, not enough to justify
inventories. But if the manufacturing of Kosher lemonade cost
substantially more, then the rule will be weakened in some nonlinear
proportion to the difference in costs. If it cost ten times as much to
make Kosher food, then the minority rule will not apply, except perhaps
in some very rich neighborhoods.
Muslims
have Kosher laws so to speak, but these are much narrower and apply
only to meat. For Muslim and Jews have near-identical slaughter rules
(all Kosher is halal for most Sunni Muslims, or was so in past
centuries, but the reverse is not true). Note that these slaughter rules
are skin-in-the-game driven, inherited from the ancient Eastern
Mediterranean [discussed in Chapter] Greek and Semitic practice to only
worship the gods if one has skin in the game, sacrifice meat to the
divinity, and eat what’s left. The Gods do not like cheap signaling.
Now
consider this manifestation of the dictatorship of the minority. In the
United Kingdom, where the (practicing) Muslim population is only three
to four percent, a very high number of the meat we find is halal. Close
to seventy percent of lamb imports from New Zealand are halal. Close to
ten percent of the chain Subway carry halal-only stores (meaning no
pork), in spite of the high costs from the loss of business of nonpork
stores. The same holds in South Africa where, with the same proportion
of Muslims, a disproportionately higher number of chicken is Halal
certified. But in the U.K. and other Christian countries, halal is not
neutral enough to reach a high level, as people may rebel against
forceful abidance to other’s religious norms. For instance, the 7th
Century Christian Arab poet Al-Akhtal made a point to never eat halal
meat, in his famous defiant poem boasting his Christianity: “I do not
eat sacrificial flesh”. (Al-Akhtal was reflecting the standard Christian
reaction from three or four centuries earlier — Christians were
tortured in pagan times by being forced to eat sacrificial meat, which
they found sacrilegious. Many Christian martyrs starved to death.)
One can expect the same rejection of religious norms to take place in the West as the Muslim populations in Europe grows.
Figure
2 Renormalization group: steps one through three (start from the top):
Four boxes containing four boxes, with one of the boxes pink at step
one, with successive applications of the minority rule.
So
the minority rule may produce a larger share of halal food in the
stores than warranted by the proportion of halal eaters in the
population, but with a headwind somewhere because some people may have a
taboo against Moslem food. But with some non-religious Kashrut rules,
so to speak, the share can be expected converge to closer to a hundred
percent (or some high number). In the U.S. and Europe, “organic” food
companies are selling more and more products precisely because of the
minority rule and because ordinary and unlabeled food may be seen by
some to contain pesticides, herbicides, and transgenic genetically
modified organisms, “GMOs” with, according to them, unknown risks. (What
we call GMOs in this context means transgenic food, entailing the
transfer of genes from a foreign organism or species). Or it could be
for some existential reasons, cautious behavior, or Burkean conservatism
–some may not want to venture too far too fast from what their
grandparents ate. Labeling something “organic” is a way to say that it
contains no transgenic GMOs.
In
promoting genetically modified food via all manner of lobbying,
purchasing of congressmen, and overt scientific propaganda (with smear
campaigns against such persons as yours truly), the big agricultural
companies foolishly believed that all they needed was to win the
majority. No, you idiots. As I said, your snap “scientific” judgment is
too naive in these type of decisions. Consider that transgenic-GMO
eaters will eat nonGMOs, but not the reverse. So it may suffice to have a
tiny, say no more than five percent of evenly spatially distributed
population of non-genetically modified eaters for the entire
population to have to eat non-GMO food. How? Say you have a corporate
event, a wedding, or a lavish party to celebrate the fall of the Saudi
Arabian regime, the bankruptcy of the rent-seeking investment bank
Goldman Sachs, or the public reviling of Ray Kotcher, chairman of
Ketchum the public relation firm that smears scientists and scientific
whistleblowers on behalf of big corporations. Do you need to send a
questionnaire asking people if they eat or don’t eat transgenic GMOs and
reserve special meals accordingly? No. You just select everything
non-GMO, provided the price difference is not consequential. And the
price difference appears to be small enough to be negligible as
(perishable) food costs in America are largely, about up to eighty or
ninety percent, determined by distribution and storage, not the cost at
the agricultural level. And as organic food (and designations such as
“natural”) is in higher demand, from the minority rule, distribution
costs decrease and the minority rule ends up accelerating in its effect.
Big
Ag (the large agricultural firms) did not realize that this is the
equivalent of entering a game in which one needed to not just win more
points than the adversary, but win ninety-seven percent of the total
points just to be safe. It is strange, once again, to see Big Ag who
spent hundreds of millions of dollars on research cum smear campaigns,
with hundreds of these scientists who think of themselves as more
intelligent than the rest of the population, miss such an elementary
point about asymmetric choices.
Another
example: do not think that the spread of automatic shifting cars is
necessarily due to the majority of drivers initially preferring
automatic; it can just be because those who can drive manual shifts can
always drive automatic, but the reciprocal is not true [1].
The
method of analysis employed here is called renormalization group, a
powerful apparatus in mathematical physics that allows us to see how
things scale up (or down). Let us examine it next –without mathematics.....