Sunday, September 21, 2025

"Can you make it to the end of this column?"

From The Economist, September 11:

Understanding the new economics of attention 

They call it brainrot. Inane short-form videos just stimulating enough to keep you watching and scrolling, in a zombie-like manner, through whatever the algorithm presents next; not quite dull enough for you to tear your monetisable eyeballs away from the screen. Viewers are ambivalent. Such content offers a way to switch off. It also offers a way to waste hours of your life.

Economists may soon start to think of brainrot as a means of theft. Increasingly, the discipline is modelling attention as a resource, alongside land, labour and capital. Attention is scarce and rivalrous in the field’s jargon; time spent on brainrot cannot be spent on something else. Focus, being vital to most forms of work, aids production and can be consumed in leisure. Getting the most out of, say, reading a newspaper column requires your full attention, which can be hard to provide if your phone is nearby.

Treating attention as a scarce resource helps bridge some of the gap between traditional models of Homo economicus—a rational optimiser seeking to maximise satisfaction of their preferences—and the figure who emerges from the experiments of behavioural economics, who is pulled away from rational thinking by any number of biases. Why do consumers consistently fall for “left-digit bias”, for instance, meaning they are far more likely to buy something for $2.99 than $3.00 while not distinguishing between items that cost $2.99 and $2.98?

Well, attention is scarce, which means that people rely on shortcuts and $2 is less than $3. Why bother to read the rest of the price? In 2003 Christopher Sims of Princeton University, later awarded a Nobel prize in economics, developed what he called a “rational inattention” model, in which optimising agents can process only so much information at a time. Such a model explains the smooth (rather than instant) adjustment of various macroeconomic variables, including interest rates and prices, to new information, he suggested. People sensibly devote just a portion of their limited attention to learning about market-moving news.

There are antecedents to this approach. Herbert Simon, who won both the Turing award for artificial intelligence in 1975 and the Nobel prize in economics in 1978, coined the term “bounded rationality”. Instead of an all-knowing optimiser, economics should model people as “satisficing”, he argued, choosing options that are simply good enough, rather than perfect, given the limits of their informational environment. “What information consumes is rather obvious: it consumes the attention of its recipients,” he wrote. “A wealth of information creates a poverty of attention and the need to allocate that attention efficiently.” Endless information distributed through smartphones creates such a world. And as Simon pointed out, unlimited wants and scarce resources are the definition of an economic problem.

Yet there are some concerns about treating attention as a resource that can be allocated along the lines of labour and capital. What counts as attention? A recent review by George Loewenstein of Carnegie Mellon University and Zachary Wojtowicz of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology defines it as the selective allocation of a scarce, rivalrous mental resource to an information-processing task. Attentional resources include working memory, selective concentration and visual focus. As Messrs Loewenstein and Wojtowicz point out, “pay attention” could either mean “look at this” or “stop daydreaming”, and following either command would mean similar, but subtly different, actions. Aggregating all of them into a single category, “attention”, comes with its own problems, as economics has discovered when putting diverse means of production into the single bucket of “capital”.....

....MUCH MORE