Thursday, March 17, 2016

JPMorgan: Why Negative Interest Rates Are Harmful

From Barron's Wall Street's Best Minds column:

David Kelly is chief global strategist with J.P. Morgan Funds, a unit of JPMorgan Chase.
The investment strategist hopes the Fed never considers moving to negative short-term rates.
For over 100 years, the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) and its predecessors have regulated pharmaceuticals in the United States. The general standard they have applied is that before a drug can be sold to the public, it has to be proven to be both “safe and effective”. The testing procedure is long and rigorous, but it has had the distinct advantage of protecting the public from quack remedies that do nothing to cure the disease for which they are prescribed and come with very serious side effects.

There is, unfortunately, no FDA to regulate the behavior of central banks and since the onset of the financial crisis in 2008, they have applied some extreme and untested forms of stimulus, first to stabilize financial markets and then to stimulate stronger economic growth.

These remedies have generally succeeded in the first task and failed in the second. The financial crisis is over. However, the economic expansions in the U.S., Europe and Japan all remain anemic by historic standards.

In response, rather than carefully reviewing the way monetary policy is interacting with the economy, central banks have pressed ahead with ever more exotic forms of stimulus, including cutting overnight rates to near zero levels, implementing quantitative easing programs and employing schemes designed almost to bribe financial institutions into lending. The most recent expansion of these policies has been the introduction of a negative interest rate policy (or NIRP) by which central banks seek to expand lending and spending by setting short-term rates at a negative level. (It should be noted that NIRP refers to an explicit central bank decision to set short-term policy rates at negative levels – many long-term government bond yields already trade at negative rates in Europe and Japan but that is not, technically, part of the policy).

The European Central Bank (or ECB) has three main policy rates. In shorthand, these include the lending rate, which is the rate it charges banks to borrow from it, the main refinancing rate, which is the rate it sets for interbank lending and the deposit rate, which is the rate it pays banks on their deposits at the ECB. In the world’s latest dose of NIRP, on March 10, the ECB cut its lending rate by 0.05% to 0.25%, the main refinancing rate from 0.05% to zero and the deposit rate by 0.1% to -0.4%.

These changes were accompanied by a further expansion and extension of its asset purchase program (now up to €80 billion per month and including some corporate bonds for the first time) and a new round of targeted long- term refinancing operations, designed to lend very cheap money to banks (in many cases with negative rates), provided those banks increase private sector lending.

In judging whether NIRP constitutes “safe and effective” monetary policy, it is important to consider first how it is supposed to help the euro zone and second the extent of its side effects.

The simplest model of how negative interest rates might work implies a full transmission of those negative rates to all rates across capital markets. When the ECB cuts its lending rate by 0.1% to -0.4%, commercial banks cut the rates they pay depositors by 0.1%, (even if it means charging depositors for the privilege of leaving money with the bank), and banks reduce the interest rates they charge borrowers by 0.1%. 

Borrowers, seeing lower available rates, are more willing to borrow money to buy a house or expand a business while savers, seeing negative rates penalizing their savings, are more willing to spend money today, boosting consumer spending. In addition, global investors, seeing only negative rates available for overnight deposits in euros, switch to other currencies pushing down the value of the euro and thereby boosting exports and increasing imported inflation.

There are, unfortunately, multiple problems with this model.

• First, many banks don’t want to charge their customers negative interest rates on deposits for the very good reason that those customers could simply withdraw their funds. Consequently, banks either have to eat the cost of receiving less on ECB deposits than they are paying on their own or actually boost lending rates. European bank stocks fell early in 2016, partly due to concerns that negative interest rates would erode bank capital. In addition, in some instances, mortgage rates and corporate bond yields have actually risen in the wake of NIRP.

• Second, to the extent that savers lose interest income from a NIRP policy, there are significant negative income effects from NIRP. The household sector around the world is generally a net lender – that is to say they have more interest-bearing assets than interest-bearing liabilities. Thus, cutting interest rates across the board actually reduces consumer net income. This may cut costs for the government and corporate sectors. However, spending by these sectors is likely less tied to income than for consumers.

• Third, very low or negative interest rates on short-term accounts clearly give households an incentive to spend rather than save. However, most of this money is likely earmarked for long-term savings and so is more likely to end up as cash in a safe or being reinvested into a financial asset rather than pumped into the real economy. Moreover, even if this promotes higher asset prices, it is not clear that this will translate into a positive “wealth effect” for consumption, as investors will also have marked down their expectations of the income that could be produced from a given stock of financial assets....
...MORE