Saturday, November 3, 2018

"The Rise of the Financial Economy"

From American Affairs Journal:
Remember auction rate securities? For decades, financial institutions hosted “auctions” of these fixed-rate instruments for buyers and sellers. They were considered so safe, and the auctions (where the interest rate would be “reset” depending on the level of interest in the securities, among other factors) so routine, that auction rate securities became an alternative to money market funds for those wanting a short-term, interest-bearing investment.

Until they weren’t. In a kind of prelude to the mortgage crisis, the auctions began “freezing up” in 2008 and “failing”—that is, sellers could not find buyers. Financial institutions had implicitly agreed to backstop the auctions by buying up excess supply, until they too simply stopped, leaving holders of auction rate securities (ARS) without a ready market. For years afterward, significant amounts of almost worthless ARS rattled around financial firms and customer inventories.

The ARS debacle is one of the few financial events of the last century that Finance in America: An Unfinished Story does not mention, but it illustrates several themes that Kevin R. Brine and Mary Poovey present as central to their study in this truly magisterial history of the American financial system. Finance in America will be the textbook for a generation or more, for those wishing to understand what has become one of America’s most prominent economic sectors. Brine and Poovey weave their themes through a detailed narrative that examines developments in corporate organization, accounting, finance, and economics from the late nineteenth century through the 2008–9 financial crisis. The book is artfully comprehensive, examining topics such as stock analysis and valuation, economic forecasting, the development of stock indices, the increased importance of data and mathematical economics, portfolio theory, Keynesianism and monetarism, and econometrics, among others. Brine and Poovey place well-known giants such as Benjamin Graham, David Dodd, and Milton Friedman in context alongside the many other contributors to the American financial system and related scholarly areas. The book is also archivally rich, drawing from textbooks, conference papers, accounting materials, and other almost forgotten material. Despite the technical nature of the subject, the book is clearly written, and its readership need not be restricted to professionals or academics.
The Mathematical Turn in Economics and Finance
Central to the story of American finance is the “mathematical turn” in economics, beginning in the twentieth century. The book features an in-depth look at the contributions of economist Irving Fisher, in particular, whose works in the early part of the twentieth century, such as The Nature of Capital and Income (1906) and The Theory of Interest (1930), brought a new focus to the study of finance. Fisher is important for a number of reasons, including the fact that his 1891 doctoral dissertation introduced the concept of marginal utility into American economic analysis. Fisher led the way in turning economics away from its relationship with philosophy and ethics toward mathematics. His definitions of “capital,” “income,” “wealth,” and “risk” were oriented toward expectations about future income, in contrast to the more static picture of value presented by neoclassical economists. Brine and Poovey also explore everything from the econometric analysis of Norwegian economists Ragnar Frisch and Tryvge Haavelmo to work done in statistics and econometrics during World War II. They then trace the subsequent transfer of these developments to financial markets through a series of conferences in the 1940s, as the nation reverted to peacetime.

But finance is not simply math. Financial economics may be able to achieve a level of theoretical precision, but as this account shows, it is not a science in the way physics is. The book acknowledges “the consolidation of finance as a gradual, uneven process without losing sight of the heterogeneity of its components or the capaciousness of what it has now become.” How one defines a balance sheet, what to include as a “capital good,” and the creation of indices or stock valuation techniques are not questions with objective answers independent of time or con text. Indeed, the discipline of “finance” on this account is largely a graft onto other disciplines such as mathematics and economics, and it also served (and continues to serve) political purposes.

In a surprisingly gripping section, Poovey and Brine recount the development of the concept of “gross national product” (GNP) in the 1930s and 1940s. As the authors show, the development of this concept came with serious methodological and conceptual challenges. For one thing, the principles of corporate accounting could not be perfectly applied to a nation; a nation’s tax revenue is not “income,” and consumption is not really national “cost.” Nevertheless, in the 1940s, economist Milton Gilbert wanted to see if consumer demand would hurt the war effort, or if the war was hurting national economic well-being; he would resolve these in the negative, arguing that using gross national product rather than net made more sense. But in doing so, Gilbert really focused on the health of government.

Others, like Simon Kuznets, had collected data on national income and production on the assumption that “the end goal of economic activity is the consumption of real goods and services; and the purpose of constructing national aggregates is to measure economic welfare.” Gilbert crucially departed from Kuznets by including a measure of expenditure as well. Gilbert’s model “implicitly equated the growth of government (expenditures and costs) with growth of the nation’s economy. . . .

When the growth of government was equated with the growth of the nation, the policy tool the national accountant provided could be used to justify government growth—and the national accountant became, de facto, an apologist for—as well as an indispensable measure of—the government he measured.” For example, Gilbert added taxes back into the gross national product, but did not include payment of interest on government debt to the cost side. This analysis supported Roosevelt’s economic proposals during the war (as Poovey and Brine note, Roosevelt proposed a budget that allocated over half the nation’s “income” to defense spending). Gilbert needed to come up with an analysis that would avoid inflation as the nation purchased goods, especially those related to the war effort, at a faster pace. This analysis, however, also drove “the policies that shaped many Americans’ experience of the war: heavy taxation, the growth of U.S. debt in the form of Treasury bonds, price controls, and the rationing of some consumer commodities.”

Indeed, ordinary Americans’ general involvement with the financial system came about in World War I, with the government’s promotion of Liberty and Victory Bonds. The authors conclude that “the first stage of the democratization of the U.S. capital markets was a function of wartime necessity, patriotism, and ‘celebrity marketing,’” a combination which Brine and Poovey imply is still very much with us.

For examples like these, at our particular economic and cultural moment, a history of finance is crucially important. Finance in America shows just how finance is affected by cultural, political, and conceptual assumptions. Kuznets and Gilbert had both developed approaches to answer questions about the national economy, but Gilbert’s was better suited to answer the question then facing the nation. This, however, implies that our understanding of economic measures inevitably changes as the critical political questions change. By including taxes for the practical reason that this was what the government had spent to win the war, GNP would naturally expand as long as taxes grew. In the run-up to 2008, and to some extent even today, the nation perhaps suffers from a different distortion: the mindset that the stock market and those companies that dominate it simply reflect the objective state of the American economy. If the “market” does well, in other words, then the nation does well. But that is not necessarily the case. This mindset, so established among both right- and left-leaning commentators, is premised on certain neoliberal presuppositions, which are more assumed than proven.
Efficient Markets and Rational Choice
Finance in America also demonstrates the periodic failures to account for irrationality in financial decision-making. As the larger events of 2008–9 unfolded, a market panic of sorts spread to the ARS market, which was not the same as the mortgage market that was suffering a loss of confidence. Nevertheless, customers sought to dump their ARS holdings because of nervousness about their creditworthiness. Other investors, for the same reason, decided not to buy ARS as they typically would. But the buyers, sellers, and the ARS themselves were largely the same the day before auctions started to freeze as they were the day after; the investors simply stopped believing in the auction market itself. This pattern recurred in other areas of the markets. Even before defaults, some market participants decided that mortgage-backed securities simply were not worth what the financial models said they were. Once that happened, the brokerage houses that had relied on the value of those instruments as collateral to finance their operations could no longer do so, leading, in part, to a downward spiral. In the abstract, every credit matches a debit. But it is best not to look down from the ladder of debt. When that happened in 2008, as John Lanchester recounted in the London Review of Books (July 5, 2018), “people suddenly started to wonder whether these assets (which by this point had been sold and resold all around the financial system so that nobody was clear who actually owned them . . .) were worth what they were supposed to be worth.”...
...MUCH MORE