Thursday, March 14, 2019

"Energy Efficiency Improvements Do Not Save Energy"

Hey, it's our old pal Jevons.
And he's brought his paradox.

From Stochastic Trend, Feb. 19:
I have a new working paper out, coauthored with Stephan Bruns and Alessio Moneta, titled: "Macroeconomic Time-Series Evidence That Energy Efficiency Improvements Do Not Save Energy". 
It's another paper from our ARC funded project: "Energy Efficiency Innovation: Diffusion, Policy and the Rebound Effect". We estimate the economy-wide effect on energy use of energy efficiency improvements in the U.S. We find that the rebound is around 100%, implying that in the long run energy efficiency improvements do not save energy or reduce greenhouse gas emissions.

At the micro level, we might naïvely expect a 1% improvement in energy efficiency to reduce energy use by 1%. But people adjust their behavior. Efficiency improvements reduce the cost of energy services like heating, transport, or lighting. Because these are now cheaper to produce, people consume more of them, and so the percentage reduction in energy use is less than the improvement in efficiency. This is known as the direct rebound effect.

People might also redirect their spending to consume more of complementary goods, like larger houses in the case of residential heating improvements, and reduce their consumption of substitute goods and services, like bus rides or cycling, in the case of car fuel economy improvements. These changes have implications for the energy used to produce these goods and services. Additionally, the reduction in demand for energy should lower the price of energy further boosting the rebound in energy use. Finally, the improvement in energy efficiency is an increase in productivity, which should result in economic growth. Higher incomes mean higher demand for energy. Adding these indirect rebound effects to the direct rebound effect we get the economy-wide rebound effect.

The size of the economy-wide rebound effect is crucial for estimating the contribution that energy efficiency improvements can make to reducing energy use and greenhouse gas emissions. Our study provides the first empirical general equilibrium estimate of the economy-wide rebound effect. Previous studies use simulation models, known as computable general equilibrium models, or partial equilibrium econometric models that don't allow the price of energy to adjust. Some of the latter studies also measure rebound incorrectly, for example assuming that energy intensity – energy used per dollar of GDP – measures energy efficiency. In fact, the majority of the rebound effect happens when energy intensity rebounds as people shift to more energy intensive consumption after an energy efficiency improvement. Economic growth induced by the efficiency improvement is expected to contribute less to total rebound.

We use a structural vector autoregressive model, or SVAR, that is estimated using search methods developed in machine learning. We apply the SVAR to U.S. monthly and quarterly data. An SVAR explains changes in the vector of variables, x, in terms of its past values and a vector of serially and mutually uncorrelated shocks, ε:

In our basic model, the vector, x, contains three variables: primary energy use, GDP, and the price of energy. The first of the shocks is a shock to energy use, holding constant shocks to GDP and the price of energy and the past values of all three variables. We think this is a reasonable definition of an energy efficiency shock. The other two shocks are income and price shocks....MORE