Monday, June 2, 2025

Stanley Fischer, Central Banker, MIT Econ. Mafioso, Has Died

From the New York Times, June 1:

Stanley Fischer, Who Helped Defuse Financial Crises, Dies at 81
He was the No. 2 at the Federal Reserve and the I.M.F. during periods of economic turmoil, and he mentored future economic leaders, like Ben Bernanke. 

Stanley Fischer, an economist and central banker whose scholarship and genial, consensus-seeking style helped guide global economic policies and defuse financial crises for decades, died on Saturday at his home in Lexington, Mass. He was 81.

The cause was complications of Alzheimer’s disease, his son Michael said.

Mr. Fischer served as the head of Israel’s central bank from 2005 to 2013, as vice chairman of the Federal Reserve Board from 2014 to 2017 and as the No. 2 officer at the International Monetary Fund from 1994 to 2001, when that agency was struggling to contain financial panics in Mexico, Russia, Asia and Latin America.

As a professor at M.I.T., he was a thesis adviser or mentor to an extraordinary range of future leaders, including Ben S. Bernanke, later chairman of the Fed; Mario Draghi, president of the European Central Bank; and Kazuo Ueda, governor of the Bank of Japan.

His former students also included two people who chaired the U.S. Council of Economic Advisers, Christina D. Romer and N. Gregory Mankiw, as well as Lawrence H. Summers, who served as secretary of the Treasury and president of Harvard University.

“He had a role in shaping a whole generation of economists and policymakers,” Mr. Bernanke said in a February 2024 interview for this obituary. That included spurring Mr. Bernanke’s initial interest in macroeconomics and monetary policy.

In 1998, The Times described Mr. Fischer as “the closest thing the world economy has to a battlefield medic.” He helped negotiate a rescue package for Russia by cellphone while standing atop a sand dune on Martha’s Vineyard, where he was on vacation.

The cures Mr. Fischer prescribed for financial crises were broadly in line with the Washington Consensus, a set of “best practices” compiled in 1989 by John Williamson, a British economist.

Those guidelines called for openness to free markets, global trade and foreign investment, among other things. Joseph E. Stiglitz, a Nobel Prize-winning economist and Columbia University professor, accused the I.M.F. of acting like a “colonial ruler” and in a 2002 interview with The Times said that the fund and the World Bank were trying to impose standard approaches that didn’t take full account of differing conditions in each country.

In a 2003 lecture on globalization, Mr. Fischer generally defended the I.M.F.’s approach by arguing that opening up to foreign trade and investment had lifted multitudes out of poverty in China and India. 

Mr. Fischer was a leader in updating the theories of the British economist John Maynard Keynes, whose calls for government intervention to steer the economy resonated from the 1930s through the 1960s but came under harsh attack in the 1970s. At that time of high inflation and low economic growth, a combination known as stagflation, economists at the University of Chicago and elsewhere argued that government intervention was likely to be self-defeating. 

Mr. Fischer’s research in the 1970s focused on that split between Keynesian economists and the Chicago school’s faith in the market. If unemployment was too high, the Keynesians argued, central banks could stimulate the economy by making the money supply grow faster. The Chicago-school economists countered that such stimulus would prompt workers to expect higher inflation and demand pay increases; the result would be faster inflation and no sustainable rise in employment.

In a 1977 paper, “Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule,” Mr. Fischer argued that wages were “sticky” because of long-term contracts and didn’t adjust immediately when a central bank changed its policy. Thus, he wrote, a well-timed stimulus program could boost job creation in the near term without igniting inflation.

“There is some room for maneuver by the monetary authorities” in steering the economy, he concluded.

His work in this area helped shape a broad agreement among intervention-minded economists under the label of New Keynesian economics.

Mr. Fischer also was chief economist of the World Bank in the late 1980s and vice chairman of Citigroup in the early 2000s. He failed in a long-shot bid to become the head of the I.M.F. in 2011, losing out to Christine Lagarde of France, partly because he exceeded the age limit for the job. At the time, he argued that he was “full of vigor” at 67 and should be given an exemption from the ceiling of 65.

Mr. Fischer was influential partly because of his diplomatic nature, Olivier Blanchard, one of his former students and later a colleague at M.I.T., wrote in 2023. Even when the field of macroeconomics “was going through wars of religion, there was no sense of ‘us versus them’ but instead an openness to alternative views,” Mr. Blanchard wrote.

After he took a break from academia in the late 1980s to work at the World Bank, Mr. Fischer was hooked on what he sometimes called his “real world” role. He relished international travel and the fast-paced demands of finding solutions for economic crises affecting billions of lives....

....MUCH MORE 

Again, some of his students/mentees:

Ben Bernanke, Mario Draghi, Kazuo Ueda, Christina Romer, N. Gregory Mankiw, and Lawrence Summers. Also IMF chief economists Olivier Blanchard, Ken Rogoff and Maurice Obstfeld.

For those keeping score here is a graphic we used in November 2013's "UPDATED--Summers, Krugman, Secular Stagnation? Seriously? (special bonus: a map of the whole MIT economics gang!)": 

https://anticap.files.wordpress.com/2013/11/econ_mitcharticle04__01__960.jpg

Note Professor Fischer's position in the web.